Enabling zero-duty imports from developing countries
- Providing duty free market access to least developed countries
Description
Context
Many LDC exports receive preferential market access under Generalised System of Preference (GSP) arrangements. Ninety-nine per cent of LDC exports, by value, now enter the EU market duty free. LDC beneficiaries receive duty-free access on all covered industrial and agricultural products, as well as on an additional list of selected agricultural products (UNCTAD, 1999). On average, between 80 and 90 per cent of LDCs' exports enter their major markets duty free and tariff preferences are in several cases, under-utilised (WTO, 1998).
Overall, the problem posed by tariffs on LDCs' existing structure of exports appear insignificant, with the exception of sensitive areas such as agriculture and textiles. More significant difficulties for market access to LDCs' existing exports are linked to non-tariff measures, such as quantitative restriction (textiles and clothing), SPS restrictions (fish and fish products, meat), standards (leather), and rules of origin, where the non-harmonised interpretation of 'substantial transformation' has restrictive market effects on products of export interest to LDCs.
Implementation
The European Community has expressed a commitment that "essentially all products" from the least developed countries should be assured tariff-free and quota-free market access to the industrialised countries. Such preferential access should be in place by the end of the New Round. The commitment would be based on the principle of Special and Differential Treatment embodied in Part IV of the GATT. As such, the commitment would represent non-reciprocal preferences, but could be linked to commitments from developing countries to adopt more MFN tariff bindings, and to efforts by GSP donor countries to expand the coverage of preferences (in line with measures under the New Round and Development).
The impact on the EU of granting free market access would be slight; although the EU is a major market for least developed countries these imports are a small share of the EU total. Consumers (including firms using the products as raw materials or intermediate inputs) would benefit from lower prices and, potentially, a wider range of products. There may be adjustment costs for small groups of producers of competing products (mostly in Southern Europe) but efficiency would be increased if such groups were supported by measures other than trade protection. The net welfare benefit to the EU would be positive, although a few producer groups may incur losses. The net global impact would be positive, at least in terms of economic and social effects.